Zero Interest Rate Policy (ZIRP) is where the central bank maintains a policy of artificially low interest rates. Interest rates may not be “zero” but the idea is that they are “nominally” zero or less when inflation is considered. Essentially, we have been in a ZIRP environment for some time. There is no historical precedent for this environment over any significant period of time.
There is an
equation, ER= I +E that can be adapted to many investment theories. ER is “expected return”. I is “interest” and E is “equity return from
dividends and capital appreciation”.
When
discussing portfolio investment allocation, one could think in terms of the “expected
return” being the sum of the return from Interest on fixed income investments
(bonds) plus the return from dividends and capital appreciation applicable to Equities
or stocks.
Another use
of the equation is the attempt to explain the “expected return” and valuation
of a particular investment, such as Equities or stocks in general. The “expected return” from owning equities or
stocks would be the return you would get from a zero risk investment, plus the “extra”
return or “risk premium” that you would earn because of the special additional
risk associated with stocks. Stocks are
generally considered to be more risky than bonds and hence investors expect a
higher return.
Generally, in
either use of the equation, I is not zero. But, in a ZIRP environment, it IS zero,
creating some strange and unusual outcomes as well as a great deal of
misunderstanding.
In the Allocation example, with I=0, ER=E, meaning the entire return from the portfolio comes from equities. In the Valuation example with I=0, ER=E meaning the expected return of the investment is equal to the “equity risk premium” associated with owning stocks.
History
teaches us that the “equity risk premium” or ERP for stocks varies depending on
many factors, but generally is in the range of 5% to 8% for the “market”. What that means is that the price of the “market”
or for an “average” stock is based on the expectation that the owner will earn
an average ERP of 6.5% per year over and above the % return per year for a “riskless”
interest bearing investment.
So let’s say
for example, we have US 10 year Treasuries
(theoretically riskless in normal times) paying 5% and the ERP of 6.5%. Then the ER or expected return would be 11.5%
per year. (This happens to be the
average return from the stock market since 1900.)
Now, let’s
say that US 10 year Treasuries are only paying 2.5%. One would expect the ERP
to stay at 6.5% and the ER would drop to 2.5+ 6.5=9%. But, what if people are concerned about
rising interest rates, where US 10 year Treasuries could fall in value. The “riskless”
interest bearing asset now becomes very short term notes that earn essentially zero
interest. In this odd case, the ER would drop to 0+6.5=6.5%.
So why would
stock markets rise more than 9% per year in an environment where the long term “expected
return” would be somewhere between 6.5% and 9% per year? The S&P500 rose significantly more than
this in 2013 and so far in 2014.
When the
alternative is 2.5% from US 10 year Treasuries, then one is paying a price of
$100 for a $2.50 return or a 40 “PE” or price/earnings ratio. In such a world, to some a price of $2000 for
stocks that earn $100 seems like a reasonable “PE” of only 20. (This is about where we are right now.)
During that
time from 1900 to 2014, when the market earned an average of 11.5%, the PE averaged
around 15. When market prices rise to a
PE of 20, the price for a dollar of return is theoretically 30% higher than
average. Put another way, the return going forward based on current prices, on
a percentage basis should be expected to be 30% less---more like 8% than 11.5%.
So, no matter
how you slice and dice, the reality is that a ZIRP, while providing a temporary
rise in prices, essentially reduces the expected future returns from saving and
investing.
Here is the
most important point…
What if ZIRP
is temporary and that “magic” formula of ER=11.5% with I equal to 5% and ER
equal to 6.5% becomes the norm again?
That means a PE of around 15 and a dramatic drop in stock prices—even assuming
that earnings and the economy remain strong.
So unless you
are one who believes that interest rates will stay below their historical
averages for the foreseeable future, you should assume that the S&P500 is
considerably overvalued—even if earnings grow at the same time that interest
rates rise. That means that you should
at least maintain a conservative asset allocation with a considerable portion
allocated to fixed income. And, a
portion of that fixed income should be liquid enough to take advantage of lower
stock prices when they “correct” back to more normal valuations.
This should
not be considered as some form of market timing strategy because when and even
if this “correction” might occur is “unknowable”. It is better to think in
terms of the proven concept of rebalancing; recognizing that markets fluctuate
between being overvalued and undervalued. Buying during periods of
undervaluation is one of the keys to being a successful investor.
An important
caution… Interest bearing fixed income
investments in a ZIRP environment can be very risky. Bonds historically are a part of the
portfolio in order to provide a stable if not even a negatively correlated return
compared to stocks. But in a transition out of a ZIRP to a normal environment,
BOTH stocks and many bonds will decline in value. In such a situation, investments that are
stable in a rising interest rate environment may be quite attractive and
valuable.
Finally, when
thinking about government sponsored ZIRP, it is true that ZIRP favors the
consumer over the investor. And, since consumers and borrowers as voters outnumber
investors and savers, one should be aware that ZIRP will be politically
acceptable until rising prices and inflation become an issue to consumers and
borrowers.
I happen to
believe that one major reason we have not seen inflation, despite central bank
stimulus is the simultaneous trend to force or “encourage” banks to raise
capital and reduce leverage. When banks have reached the politically acceptable
level of capitalization, money velocity and inflation will likely increase
considerably. When this will occur is a
bit of a mystery—even to the central bankers. But, when it does ZIRP will end.
No comments:
Post a Comment